Key Takeaways
- The
promotion of New Quality Productive Forces (NQPF) seems set to become the
bedrock of the Fifteenth Five Year Plan which, if it follows previous
timescales, will run from 2026 to 2030.
- As
is often the case in China, Xi has announced a big picture grand vision which
is short on details. More specific plans and policies will emerge to support
the vision over time.
- At
the most basic level, it can be viewed as a combination of previous initiatives
designed to promote High Quality Development (rather than just high rates of
growth) with ever increasing concerns about economic insecurities and
vulnerabilities.
- However,
the intention is to show that this is not just a change in priorities, but a
paradigmatic shift in the essential nature of the Chinese economy.
- In
the long run, the aim is for technological progress in innovation to become the
source of growth (rather than increased capital or labour inputs).
- Even
if the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) can manage the process of change
successfully in the long run, there are likely to be significant dislocations
and significant pain for some in the short run.
- As
the aspiration evolves into policy, it is likely to impact on European
companies both in terms of their ability to produce in/sell to China, and in
terms of competition from Chinese high-tech producers in other markets.
Introduction
The
Xi Jinping era has not been short of new concepts and buzzwords. If we just
focus on economics alone, in addition to Xi’s grand visions for new
international interactions and orders, we have seen at various times a focus on
‘Supply-side structural reform 供给侧改革’, ‘High quality development 高质量发展’,
‘Made
in China 2025’ (MIC2025) and ‘Dual Circulation 国内国际双循环’.
Xi has also (in theory at least) shifted the entire focus of the CCP’s economic
objectives and endeavours by placing a greater emphasis on the quality,
utility, and sustainability of growth and away from ‘GDPism‘,[1]
or growth for growth’s sake.
Given all that has already been said - and not
least by Xi himself - does the recent emphasis on New Quality Productive Forces
(NQPF) add anything new? As we will explain, in some respects, it is an
updating or expansion or intensification of what we have already heard overlaid
with (or integrated with) an increasing concern with economic insecurity. The
need to de-risk China’s economic future and in Xi’s
words ‘better safeguard China's new pattern
of development’ points to the need to decrease China’s reliance on
imported goods and components, and particularly of high quality and hi-tech
ones; an objective that is also at the heart of both MIC2025 and Dual
circulation.
That said, for Marxists, the language of
‘new productive forces’ (NPF) is hugely significant. It points to not just a
change of emphasis or policy within an existing economic structure, but a
fundamental change in the nature of that economic structure itself. NQPF, then,
captures the essence of previous concepts and (alongside the shift in the
principal contradiction) establishes the idea of a paradigm shift. So it needs to be taken seriously as an expression of the
Chinese leadership’s preferred and desired direction of travel. If successful,
it would also have massive implications for the structure of global production
networks, and the distribution of knowledge and political power within those
networks too.
Desiring something, though, does not (on
its own) guarantee its delivery. Making such a paradigmatic change is not
problem free, and resolving old problems and is likely to generate new ones
along the way. Moreover, if implemented in a certain way, the NQPF agenda might
even exacerbate some of the problems that it in part designed to resolve. Making
a successful paradigmatic change, then, is likely to require a skilful
management of the ways that the CCP justifies its rule, and the capability and
willingness to deal with new challenges ahead.
Paradigmatic Change: Marxism and NPF
It can often take time for a preferred
and official English language translation of a new Chinese concept to emerge.[2]
When it rose to prominence as the leitmotif of the annual Two
Sessions meetings (of the National People’s Congress and
the Chinese People’s Political Consultative Conference) in 2024, what in
Chinese is called 新质生产力(xin zhi shengchan li) was translated in English language outlets both as NPF and NQPF.Both translations were also then
subsequently used by foreign English language reporting and analysis too. The two versions remain in use in English
today, but the latter seems to have become the more common official translation.[3] This means that the
crucial difference in the two that is obvious in the original Chinese – the
inclusion of the character 质 (zhi) for quality – is not always evident in some
English language discussions.
Nevertheless, despite this difference, the original Marxist
understanding of NPF is clearly significant and helps us understand the full
extent of what NQPF is meant to convey. NPF
was used by Marx and Engels to refer to a fundamental epochal paradigm shift in
the basis of economic activity; for example, the transition from feudalism to
capitalism. The key here then is the identification of the nature of the
economic transition taking place. This is not just about tinkering at the
margins or a shift in emphasis within an existing paradigm, but
rather a change from one mode of production to an entirely new one.
Here,
perhaps the thinking of later and post-Marxists is more salient for the contemporary
Chinese case than the original Marxist thinking. For example, Fred
Block and Larry Hirschhorn refer to the key
shift that took place in production in the USA in the 1920s and the move
towards a post-industrial era. Growth was no longer simply and only the result
of an increase in labour or capital (or both) as it had been in the past, but
of a qualitative and fundamental shift in the basis of production; ‘a quantum
change in the extent to which conscious intervention shapes and reshapes
production’. This change was the result of the:
importance
of such ‘background’ factors as information, new modes of management,
technological advances, and the expansion of services, such as education,
welfare, and medical care.
When Chinese economists talk about NQPF as ‘advanced productivity freed from
traditional economic growth models’, this is what they mean. As the influential
Chinese economist Yao Yang explains, in the past, to different degrees and at different
times, Chinese growth had been driven by both the increase in labour engaged in
non-agricultural activity, and/or the expansion of capital. In the future, with
the emphasis on NQPF, this will no longer be the case. Such paradigmatic change
does not happen overnight, and there is a period when the new and old co-exist;
a period that Marx thought was inherently political and socially destabilizing.
So as Yao Yang explains, old sources of growth will not immediately disappear.
Eventually, though, if the promotion of NQPF is successful, China will have an
economy ‘where per
capita income growth relies entirely on technological progress.’ A focus on the amount of growth has been
replaced by a focus on the quality of that growth and the promotion of another of Xi Jinping’s
favoured concepts; ‘high quality development’ (HQD).
After
the annual National People’s Congress meeting in March 2024, this HQD
was defined as ‘innovative,
coordinated, green, open and shared development’ no longer driven by ‘labor,
capital and land’ but instead on innovation and ‘information technology, big
data and artificial intelligence’ where ‘obsolete production capacity and
technology will gradually be phased out’ and replaced by ‘a new pattern of
innovation-driven, green development’.
The
idea of an epochal change is reinforced by explicitly linking HQD and NQPF to
the previous change in the Principal Contradiction. As explored in some detail
in an earlier EuroHub4Sino paper on ideological change in China, this
refers to identifying the single biggest challenge to the continuation of party
rule at any given time; a challenge that is existential in nature if it is not
correctly dealt with. This principal contradiction had previously been defined
as ‘the ever-growing material needs of the people and backward social
production’ resulting in a focus on doing whatever was needed to increase
production; a focus on growth above all else or GDPism. In 2017, this was
changed to ‘the gap between unbalanced and inadequate development and people’s
ever-growing need for a better life’ indicating a transition in focus from the
quantity to the quality of growth. This was based in part on an understanding
that the old growth model was not environmentally, economically or societally
sustainable. But it wasn’t just about the future. It was also in part inspired
by an assessment that it had already created or exacerbated instabilities and
inequities that could undermine economic, environmental, societal and political
stability that now urgently needed to be dealt with.
Xi
was far not the first person to decide that the old model had reached its
shelf-life. Almost from the onset of Hu Jintao’s leadership in 2002, he
emphasised the need to replace the
old GDP-oriented growth model
with a ‘scientific concept of development’ and a call to ‘put people first’
(rather than putting raising GDP first as had previously been the case). Had it
not been for the need to act quickly to boost the economy as exports collapsed
during the global financial crisis, perhaps more would have been done sooner.
That said, when Xi replaced Hu in 2012, the
argument that strong vested interests had
stymied Hu’s ambitions, and Xi would now have to face them down to make any
progress, had a number of adherents; a view that is now officially endorsed by
the party itself. And what he has done since
then to consolidate power – the party’s power over the economy and society and
his power over the party – gives that argument some credence.
Situating NQPF in Xi’s Wisdom
As
with many things in Xi’s China, the contribution of other post-Mao (and
certainly post-Deng) leaders tend to be downplayed, and Xi’s thinking and
innovations are emphasised. NQPF is no exception.Despite building on the
thinking (and also some practice) of previous leaders, it is a concept that is
very much identified as originating with Xi. It was first
mentioned by Xi during his inspection tour of
Heilongjiang (one of China’s earliest centres of heavy industrial
development) in September 2023 with a call to:
Integrate
technological innovation resources to lead the development of strategic
emerging industries and future industries, accelerating the formation of NQPF.
It became clear that
this concept had been given particular significance when it was the subject of
the 11th collective study session of the Politburo on January 31,
2024. Xi further elaborated on NQPF and established it
as the new guiding theory for achieving HQD:
NQPF prioritize
innovation, breaking away from traditional economic growth patterns and
production development paths. They are characterized by high
technology, efficiency, and quality, embodying the advanced productive forces
consistent with the new development philosophy. NQPF are brought forth by
revolutionary technological breakthroughs, innovative allocation of production
factors, and profound transformation and upgrading of industries [emphasis
added].
Innovation and Continuity
Despite the emphasis placed on NQPF to transcend the existing
economic development and make a transition to a ‘new’ model and era, its main
objective is not particularly innovative. In many respects, it is an updating of
the aspirations and goals that the MIC2025 initiative was meant to
achieve when it was launched in 2015. This was a document and announcement that
was widely seen from outside China as the starting gun for a new race to change the nature of the global
economic order by making ‘China dominant in global high-tech manufacturing’. In the short term,
though, and from Chinese perspectives, it was more about rectifying weaknesses
and catching up than it was about dominating. The
original document blueprint pointed to considerable weaknesses in an economy
where the ‘manufacturing industry is large but not strong’ and ‘there is still
a big gap compared with advanced countries’. Innovation capability was
described as ‘weak’ with a high dependence on imported components in ‘core
technologies and high-end equipment’, and overall product quality was ‘not
high’. Global brands were still lacking, resource and energy utilization were
low and industrial pollution high, the level of informatization was low, the
degree of industrial internationalization not high, and ‘the ability of
enterprises to operate globally is insufficient’. Hence the (rather urgent)
need to overcome these deficiencies and start producing more higher quality and
hi-tech goods at home utilising Chinese knowledge, skills and innovation.
If the
promotion of NQPF is in part an updating of the MIC agenda, it is also in part
an upgrading and updating of the ‘dual circulation’
strategy. This too is
identified as Xi Jinping’s brainchild. First proposed during the seventh meeting of the Central
Financial and Economic Affairs Commission in April 2020, it was given the
status of China’sfundamental economic development strategy during the 14th Five-Year Plan period
and beyond. It was defined as:
Accelerating the establishment of a new development
paradigm with domestic circulation as the main focus, and with domestic and
international circulations mutually reinforcing each other.
One emphasis, then,
was on promoting domestic consumption, another crucial objective of the ‘dual circulation’ is to ensure a higher
level of self-sufficiency through innovation. This would naturally aid China’s
ascent up the industrial value chain, enabling the manufacturing of high
value-added products. In this regard, as Alicia García-Herrero notes, MIC2025 is a key part of the ‘dual
circulation’ strategy by seeking to replace imported ‘high-end goods’ with
domestically produced ones. And as she also notes, if successful ‘China will no longer need to import high-end inputs’ which will
have ‘obvious negative consequences for major exporters of technology, such as
Germany, Japan, South Korea, and the US’.
Building upon this foundation, NQPF further expand and
elaborate upon the connotation of innovation by emphasizing the necessity to
strengthen the original and revolutionary technological innovation. The prioritization of
advanced technological innovation is also based on national economic securityconsiderations:
Utilizing technological innovation to propel
productivity transition is a focal point of great power competition. ...
Driving productivity through innovation is an essential pathway to achieve
self-reliance, shape national competitive advantages, and safeguard national
economic security.
And when national
economic security is being discussed in China, broader understandings of
national (and regime) security are never far away.
Securitizing China’s (Economic) Future
Security looms large in all of the various
initiatives and slogans designed to upgrade the economic base. The Asian
Financial Crisis of 1997 spurred a new interest in
economic security in China,
as the potentially negative consequences of being integrated into the global
political economy became clear for pretty much for the first time since the
start of the reform era. Encouraging foreign investment to produce exports for
foreign markets was all well and good when the regional and/or global economy
was thriving. However, growth and employment in China (and therefore regime
legitimacy) were threatened when events outside China’s control resulted in
either a reduction in investment or demand (or both).
Moreover, it is not just purely economic
fluctuations that create insecurity. There has long been a concern in China
that hostile states might try and prevent China’s rise by intervening in the
global economy to cut off or limit supplies of key resources and/or
manufacturing inputs, or to restrict access to lucrative overseas markets.
Indeed, trying to depoliticise
international economic interactions was one
of the reasons
that China’s leaders sought to join the WTO back in the 1990s. When it did join
in 2001, there was an expectation (and not just in China) that it would be
awarded market economy status after 15 years of membership. This would have
resulted in a big shift in the sort of evidence required by others when
bringing cases of unfair Chinese practices to the WTO and made it somewhat
easier for Chinese defendants to defend themselves. The lack of such
recognition in 2016 by the United States and the European Union generated
annoyance in China that the goal-posts seemed to be being moved by the major
powers, and that political considerations and geostrategic competition might
continue to influence China’s ability to act in the global economy in the
future.
That
is exactly what seems to have happened. Zimmerman
argues that the introduction of the Foreign Investment Risk Review
Modernization Act in 2018 to update the jurisdiction and scope of investment
screening was a direct result of ‘increased fear regarding China’s growing
strategic and economic clout and the potential loss of American technology
supremacy’. President
Trump’s America First strategy did not target China alone, but it’s fair to say
that Chinese imports and the US trade deficit with China held a particular
importance. Biden’s introduction of first restrictions on certain high-tech
exports to China (most notably semiconductors) in 2022 and then investments in
China in ‘sensitive’ areas the following year pointed to a bipartisan consensus
on China. That the export controls included not just things made in the US, but
also anything made anywhere in the world using Chinese tools, ‘vastly expanding‘ the US
government’s ‘reach in its attempt to slow Beijing’s technological and military
advances.
And it
is not just the US that is seen as the problem. In the EU, we can add the postponement (at least) of the introduction of the EU-China Investment Agreement and
the EU’s plans to
increase ‘scrutiny of foreign investments and [introduce] more coordinated
controls on exports and outflows of technologies to rivals such as China’. At
the national level, the introduction of national investment screening laws in countries
like Sweden and
the UK both
reflect and also reinforce a more general increase in negative views of China
and the need to de-risk
relations with China. All of these have individually and collectively been
taken in China as pointing to a future where political rather than economic logics will likely prevent Chinese actors from
getting what they want in and from the global economy. And in the process,
prevent China from developing in the way that its leaders want it to develop.
Ambitions with contradictions
In some ways it is a bit surprising that Xi
has chosen the language of developing new productive forces (with or without
quality) to describe what’s next for China. Here we need to turn to the
political consequences of epochal change and not their content and form. For
Marx and Engels, such a paradigmatic transition was the key determinant of social
dislocations and political transformations; and thus ultimately of revolution
and the collapse of the existing order. As Marx argued in ‘The Poverty of Philosophy’
in 1847:
In acquiring new
productive forces men change their mode of production; and in changing their
mode of production, in changing the way of earning their living, they change
all their social relations.
In essence, NPF disrupt
the existing patterns of social interaction and hierarchy and are incompatible
with the status-quo ante system of privilege, hierarchy and order.[4]
And while the original Marxist concern is with those NPF that replaced
feudalism under the bourgeoisie), the transition to the sort of NPFs that are
associated with HQD have also long since been identified by those
in the Marxist tradition as generating a new
version of ‘the classic Marxian formulation of a conflict between new
productive forces and old social relations of production’. As technology comes
to the fore, this results in unemployment
and underemployment and deskilling and a general ‘decay in old social patterns‘.
The
official position is that NQPF will not result in turmoil but on the contrary
will benefit all and lead to common prosperity. This is no surprise at all. The
CCP has had to cope with a major ideological and practical dilemma ever since
it took power in 1949. To put it over-simply, Marx thought that the revolution
that would lead to communism would occur as a consequence of industrialisation;
an industrialisation that had yet to occur when the CCP seized the reins of
power. This meant that the CCP was faced with trying to build a ‘modern’
industrialized economy whilst not allowing this to lead to the alienation,
class conflict and ultimately revolution that Marx had predicted. Indeed, they
wanted the process of economic change to bolster and reinforce support for the
political system, rather than generate opposition to it. And this is still the
desire today. The goal is to somehow control the social and political
consequences of economic change to minimize negative consequences and ensure
regime survival.
Even
if it does manage to do this in the long run – and that has to be a very big IF
– then there are inevitably going to be short term dislocations as ‘obsolete’
industries are let go. As Chi
Lo argues, ‘this process is inherently deflationary because the rate of destruction
is faster than the rate of creation’. It will be a process that will bring pain
to many of those in the old obsolete sectors and a key question is whether the
leadership has the will and confidence in itself and its own position to live
with this pain during the transitional process (at the very least). Notably,
there is no even geographic spread of different types of economic activity across
the country. Some areas are much more dependent on old and obsolescent
industries than others, and so any pain is likely to be unevenly distributed
too.
An Achievable Aspiration?
And yet it is far from clear how that pain can be (quickly) ameliorated,
let alone cured. Nor is it clear how NQPF can deal with the structural
deficiencies of China’s economic development that ‘dual
circulation’ was originally designed to overcome. As the crisis in China’s real
estate sector (which contributes approximately
20% of GDP) has been unfolding, finding immediate
and effective solutions to stabilizing and revitalizing it remain
elusive.
Unless
the CCP leadership is happy to cope with the consequences of a much lower
growth rate (at the very least during an interim transition period), ensuring a
stable and decent GDP growth requires the creative exploration of alternative
compensatory measures within the three
pillars underpinning China’s economic
development; domestic consumption, investment, and net exports. Given that one
of the fundamental objectives of ‘dual
circulation’ is to elevate domestic consumption as the primary driver of
economic growth, resorting to exports to fill a ‘growth gap’ (as China has done
in the past) is not an optimal choice. On the other hand, the sluggishness of
China’s domestic consumption is a longstanding issue. China embarked on efforts
to rebalance its
economic growth model by attempting to boost domestic consumption as early as
two decades ago, but with limited success. In 2004, consumption
accounted for 55.2% of GDP, compared to a decline to 53% in 2022. As The
Economist points out, ‘even among emerging
economies, China stands out: it consumed 7% less per person than Brazil in
2022, though it produced about 40% more.’
Despite
concerns about existing levels of debt in China – and particularly of local government debt –
this places a heavy emphasis on investment to
keep the economy afloat. Indeed, substantial investments
have already been made in both infrastructure and
technological innovations aiming
to offset the stagnation in the real estate market and subdued domestic consumption.
Investment
driven by the NQPF agenda primarily constitutes supply-side adjustments. More
than that, this is not a just an economic or technological driven evolution; it
is an example of the sort of governance via a politically
mobilized campaign that has become quite familiar under
Xi (with echoes of other forms of mobilization to attain other ends in previous
eras too). A big vision is announced; or more accurately, after originally being introduced in some
forum or another, a big vision is subsequently promoted to the Chinese people
with considerable fanfare. It is then discussed and repeated by other CCP
leaders, think tanks and academics, and disseminated through the media and
across Chinese cyberspace. The population is expected to embrace and endorse
it, and those who can are expected to do all that they can to support and
promote it.
It
is reasonable to expect that there will be a positive response to this
campaign; particularly (but not only) if resources are provided to support the
ambition and if it also becomes a core aim of the next Five Year Plan (due to
commence in 2026). This suggests that new (and quality) capacity will be built
across the country in response. Indeed, it is possible that there will be
overcapacity as local governments seek to respond to the campaign and boost
their own local NQPF.
Xi
himself has acknowledged the potential
consequences of local governments responding too positively to the campaign.
One danger is ‘neglecting or abandoning
traditional industries’ which Han
Wenxiu (one of
China’s key economic policy planners) notes remain ‘the main sources of
employment, income, and livelihood security’.
Another danger is that they compete
with each other to develop the same NQPF. Hence, the need for each locality to
develop their own bespoke and locally specific NQPF that are based on what Han
calls ‘actual conditions, avoiding
blind conformity and bubbles” that are built on ‘local resource endowments,
industrial foundations, scientific research conditions, and ecological
environment’.
China’s
leaders, then, are very much aware of potential pitfalls. Even so, questioning how
these new capacities can be absorbed whilst also meeting the new principal
contradiction’s objectives seems a valid question to ask. To put it simply,
where will the demand come from, and how will it meet the ‘people’s
ever-growing need for a better life’?
Although
NQPF emphasizes the transformation of technological innovation into real
economic development, it remains debatable if
and how emerging technologies can be effectively used to promote development in
real economy. While technological development ultimately contributes to the
development of humankind, its impact on actual individual human being remains
uncertain. As argued by Andrew
Cainey and Christiane Prange:
Deploying
technology can help, but breakthrough innovations … will do little to increase
living standards for most of China’s population.If
successful, Xi’s prioritization of advanced technologies may reduce China’s
dependence on overseas suppliers, but it will have limited benefits for growth
across the whole economy.
If thetechnological
innovation emphasized in NQPF cannot significantly elevate living standards and
consequently stimulate consumption and the absorption of increased supply, the extra
capacity of supply inevitably must seek channels somewhere else beyond China
for utilization or deployment. Given the desire to reduce the significance of
net exports as a driver of Chinese economic growth, this would present
something of a paradox for Chinese policy makers.
Just
as China’s economic growth model must transition from quantity to quality, so
too must the demand for human capital. In addition to the significant
constraints faced by technological development
itself, a crucial refraining factor is the shortage of human capital to support
technological innovation. According to Scott
Rozelle and Natalie Hell, China faces substantial
difficulties in meeting the requirements for high-tech innovation talent aligned
with NQPF. ‘Currently about 70 percent of the Chinese labor force is
‘unskilled’ – with no more than a junior high school education.’ In the same
vein, as demonstrated in a report
by CSIS and Brookings, according to Guidelines for
the Development of Talent in the Manufacturing Industry, ‘China will face a
talent demand gap of nearly 30 million workers by 2025 in 10 key areas of
China’s manufacturing industry, or a 48 percent shortage of skilled workers to
meet demand.’However,
addressing this human capital gap proves challenging due to various structural
constraints in China. As observed in the report, these constraints include the
hukou system[5] that impedes social
mobility, urban-rural inequality, the quality of education, and so on. As a
result, the path from NPF to N ‘Quality’ PF evolution is riddled with challenges.
Conclusions
Of course, things can change. None of
this necessarily precludes the possibility of China achieving structural
changes in its economic growth model through technological innovation – though
extremely difficult and challenging – as theorized in Joseph Schumpeter’s theory
of innovation, thereby generating new demands that
are currently beyond our comprehension.
Moreover
and more important, all of these potential challenges and adverse consequences
are very evident to Chinese analysts and policy makers too. Indeed, much of
what we have said above is based on what has been said within China. We are
still very much in the early days of the development of NQPF as an actual
strategy rather than just a mobilizing and aspirational slogan. Further
refinement and explanation will take place during the focus on economic reform
at the central committee plenum in the Summer of 2024, leading towards the new
Five Year Plan which is due to be unveiled in 2025. So we can expect more
practical and specific projects and policies to be developed to put more
practical flesh on the bones of what developing NQPF actually entails as that
Plan itself is developed. For the Chinese leadership, a key question is how
national (economic security) logics can be reconciled with the aim of improving
people’s lives, particularly during a time of transition. Unless, of course,
they can persuade the people that ensuring this security is part and parcel of
what they need for a better life.
In
the rush to think how Europe and other parts of the West might de-risk
economic relations with China, perhaps the Chinese desire to de-risk China’s
economic future has at times been a bit overlooked. To be sure, this is not the
only aim of the NQPF agenda, but it is certainly part of it. In the long run,
it might also create new challenges for those who currently dominate high-tech
production, as they find new Chinese competitors not just in China, but also in
other markets too (including at home). However the NQPF agenda evolves, it is going
to have significance – and not just economic significance – way beyond China’s
own borders.
Photo Credit: doomu - Freepik.com
|
Funded by the European Union. Views and opinions expressed are however those of the author(s) only and do not necessarily reflect those of the European Union or European Research Executive Agency (REA). Neither the European Union nor the granting authority can be held responsible for them.
|
[1]Defined as ‘the
government’s intense focus on a single measure of development, the pursuit of
strong numbers on that measure, and the overlooking of the negative
consequences of that limited vision’.
[2] As He
shows, the same is true when it comes to translating foreign political
concepts and ideas into Chinese.
[3]Though in Cowhig’s extremely
useful translations of Chinese debates, he favours ‘New
Quality Productivity’.
[4] These arguments are
fleshed out by Marx in Critique of Political Economy (1859), and by Engels in On Ludwig Feuerbach and the End of Classical German Philosophy (1866),
Anti-Dühring (1877),
and Socialism: Utopian and Scientific (1880).
[5] Where Chinese citizens have to register as a resident of a specific
jurisdiction – normally where they were born – which then places restrictions
on where they can live and work. There have been numerous promises
to reform the hukou system over the years, and some provinces are currently
piloting new more
flexible policies.